The long and winding road of John McCain
About Me
- Vic Volpe
- Los Angeles, California, United States
- The blog 'Breaking Bread' is for a civil general discussion, like you might have at the dinner table with guests. The posts 'Economics Without the B.S.' are intended for a general audience that wouldn't have to know the difference between a Phillips Curve, a Laffer Curve, or a Cole Hamels Curve. Vic Volpe was formally educated at Penn State and the University of Scranton, with major studies in History, Economics and Finance, and Business; and, is self-educated since by way of books and on-line university courses. His practical education came from sixty years of work experience in the blue-collar trades as well as a white-collar professional career -- a white-collar professional career in production and R&D. In his professional career and as a long-haul trucker, he has traveled throughout the lower forty-eight. From his professional career alone he has visited many manufacturing plants in the United States, Europe and China. He has lived in major metropolitan areas and very small towns in various parts of the United States. He served three years with the U.S. Army as an enlisted man, much of that time in Germany.
Thursday, August 30, 2018
Monday, August 13, 2018
U.S. Historical Economic Performance after World War II GDP 1947 to 2017
U.S. Historical Economic Performance
after World War II
GDP 1947 to 2017
after World War II
GDP 1947 to 2017
United States Historical Economic Performance (GDP) 1790 to 2018
U.S. Historical Economic Performance
GDP 1790 to 2018
GDP 1790 to 2018
Economics Without The B.S.**:
[** Double entendre intended.]
[** Double entendre intended.]
Wednesday, June 27, 2018
Inequality and Economic Performance
Inequality and Economic Performance
Economics Without The B.S.**:
[** Double entendre intended.]
[** Double entendre intended.]
The
Gini Ratio is one measure of inequality -- the lower the ratio the less
inequality. Notice the 1960s, especially the mid-'60s, it is the best rate of
economic growth in U.S. history; it also had a wide dispersion of wealth in
that society, by income.
Friday, April 20, 2018
Do Trade Deficits Matter for the United States?
Do Trade Deficits Matter
for the United States?
for the United States?
Economics Without The B.S.**:
[** Double entendre intended.]
[** Double entendre intended.]
The manner in which a
country conducts foreign trade is a reflection of its economy, its macro economy. While the United States has run very high
trade imbalances, about $500 billion each year or 3% of its real GDP, these
deficits were primarily due to the trade of goods, a $700 billion deficit, not
the trade of services which has consistently through the decades been in
surplus, currently at approximately $200 billion.
Our trade deficit
position took a change after the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997 and the entry
of China getting international trading status from the WTO (World Trade
Organization) in 2001. Since that time
Asian countries, and in particular China, have adopted an industrial policy of
being net trade exporting countries. And
the United States has willingly become the receptor of this international trade
imbalance in goods by being the deficit nation; and, allowing itself to expand
its consumption of goods beyond its productive capacity, which in the U.S. case
is financed by the huge inflows of foreign investment in our productive assets
at home as well as huge investments in our financial assets – U.S. treasuries, currency, agency bonds and
Wall Street created financial instruments (like CDOs, Collateralized Debt
Obligations) and their derivative products.
In addition to trade deficits that need to be financed, the United
States runs up huge Federal Government deficits of $400 to $600 billion each
year which also need to be financed.
This situation is a
reflection of the productive capacity – I would say a declining rate of
productivity – of the United States. The
1960s was the highest performing economy for a peacetime period in the entire
U.S. history – as measured by real GDP per capita, averaging approximately 3.5%
per year; over 5% per year on a real GDP basis.
Since that time we have been in a declining trendline in the rate of
productivity each succeeding decade – the 1980s and 1970s are worse than the
1960s, the 1990s are worse than the 1980s, and the last 17 years are worse than
the 1990s and
approximately one-third of the growth rate of the 1960s. While GDP is an imperfect measure of our
productivity, it is still the main measure we use. And while GDP is not a measure of our
standard of living, it is closely associated with it – the more you can
produce, the more you can consume.
We have had declining
productivity growth since the 1960s (the best period for peacetime productivity
growth in the 220+ years of history of the U.S. as measured by real GDP per
capita) and trade has been a drag on our productive growth because we now have
sectors within our economy which are less productive than what we had back in
the 1960s – a larger consumer/retail/wholesale sector, more service industries;
while having a smaller but highly productive industrial/commercial/agricultural
sectors and a small sector of highly productive business/info tech service
industries. With fewer high growth
opportunities to invest in the real economy, foreigners invest in financial
assets. Trade is not the only thing
dragging down the GDP rate of growth, nor is it the most important; but, it is
systematic of our productive base today.
When investment from
foreigners come back into the U.S. to finance our twin deficits of trade and
budget, it does make a difference how that investment is spent. Just as a business evaluates capital spending
to determine what the best investment return will be, so must the same be true
for dollars coming back into the U.S.
Even when they come back into U.S. treasuries they are financing our
government debt; so, that makes a difference if it is financing welfare or
consumption spending or defense spending on military technology or some other
capital improvement the government is making.
The foreigners investing in our government treasuries may be doing it
because they seek safety rather than the risk associated with capital
investments – that’s all well and good for them, but it is not the best outcome
for us even though it is a positive outcome for us. The better the return on the investment, the
better off we are; and, usually that will mean an investment in highly productive
resources rather than consumption spending.
In a world of limited
resources, how those resources are allocated (over time) matters. What individual actions acquire in a
transaction and how they use that acquisition affects others in that society
and determines the outcome for that society.
Our American predecessors took on an obligation, to themselves and their
society, to strive for the best and be in the vanguard of leadership in
accepting challenges. Each generation of
Americans that come along get to decide what path toward progress they will
take. The collective will of a people is
not just decided by independent individual choices but by the interaction with
others and the leadership (government, business, civic) in that society.
Saturday, March 10, 2018
Will Artificial Intelligence take over for Humans?
Will Artificial Intelligence take over for Humans?
Economics Without The B.S.**:
[** Double entendre intended.]
[** Double entendre intended.]
With all the chatter
about Artificial Intelligence taking over with neural networks and deep
learning, will machines ever duplicate the complexities of humans for melding
mind with heart for abstract creations? From Jacob Bronowski's
TV show of the 1970s, 'The Asceent of Man', at the Watts Towers in Los Angeles
--
Wednesday, March 7, 2018
The GDP/Productivity Paradox -- Real?... or Off the Mark?
The GDP Paradox --
Real?... Or Off The Mark?
Real?... Or Off The Mark?
Economics Without The B.S.**:
[** Double entendre intended.]
[** Double entendre intended.]
Our rate of productivity growth, as measured by GDP, has been on a declining trendline since the 1960s, our best peacetime economic growth in our 200+ years of history. And it has gotten worse since 2000, during our information technology age. Some of our "experts" say we do not have a productivity growth problem but a measurement problem by relying on GDP, an indiciator left over from our industrial economy age when we are now in a new information technology age.
I disagree
that the GDP paradox is a measurement problem. I am not denying that
there is a measurement issue, just that it is a side issue to the overall
problem of lackluster productivity gains. I would normally make an
argument that in addition to the GDP rate of increase showing a negatively
sloping trendline over the past several decades, you also have downward sloping
trendlines for expansion of industrial capacity, investment in plant &
equipment, R&D, education, labor productivity, multifactor productivity, all in declining trendlines for a number of
years, even before the Great Recession. I thought Hal Varian had good
explanations for why these trends exist, and not denying that they were trends,
and added interesting comments about capital formation for the newer
technologies versus more traditional enterprises. So let me skip
those issues.
I also thought Hal Varian had a good discussion of the
diffusion problem – with the diffusion of the technology advantage only slowly
rippling its way through our economy, although Varian sees this improving as we
go further. An excellent
point was made about optimizing the use of the newer technologies, “we have to figure
out a way to get the BEST use of it”; with a mention about Gordon's thinking we
have reached a point where we will no longer get a productivity bump out of the
information technology. Varian’s reply that
we are not there yet and what we have is “failure of imagination” I thought was
right on the mark. This diffusion
problem shows up not just in a sector analysis of our economy, but you can also
see it geographically played out with only a few metro areas (usually around 25
out of almost 400 metro areas nationally) that have high GDP productivity
(about half of the nation’s GDP) while much of the rest of the nation suffers
from below average GDP performance. And
my point regarding diffusion would be here is a technology, information
technology, that lends itself to being geographically distributed (especially
since much of it is centered in the service sector), in contrast with the
manufacturing environment (with hubs and long logistic supply chains) and yet
we see info tech centers of excellence highly concentrated in just a few
geographic areas around the country. And
we are a nation with educational resources spread out around the countryside,
to include rural areas, so you just must wonder if we are taking full advantage
of the resources we have to dedicate to the issue and get everyone up to speed.
But let’s take on the GDP measurement problem more
indirectly. Let’s use measurements not
affected by all this other nonsense of what gets measured and what
doesn’t. If we are doing so good today
with productivity because of the free resources that liberate prior cost
restraints and result in newborn efficiencies from the phantom productivity, WHERE ARE THE JOBS? The 10 years of the 1960s with annual rates
of real GDP growth that are almost 3x greater than the past 17 years and a
workforce that was less than half what ours is, produced (had a net gain: jobs added
minus jobs lost) over 17 million jobs – the 17 years of Bush/Obama/and 11
months of Trump have a net gain of less than 15 million; even if you add the 6
million job openings that only gets you to a little over 20 million, still not
a good comparison with the ‘60s with half the workforce. Take 1965 with a workforce of approximately
75 million, it produced more jobs than 2016 with a workforce of almost 160
million (2.9 million vs 2.2 million); and it is likely that 2016 will be better
than 2017. And I use 1965 because that
is before the Vietnam buildup influences the economy.
This is the creative/destruction argument of the
impact of technological innovation in a nutshell. The 1960s were just as dynamic as what we
have been going through in the last 25 years.
In the 1960s we had the destruction, but we also had the creation; and,
a long sustained booming economy with the productivity gains widely shared in
society. In the last 25 years we have
had the destruction, but only a tepid creative recovery; and, the productivity
gains have resulted in a maldistribution of wealth with increased inequality in
comparison to the ‘60s. The job creation
has been a lot weaker and as Varian has said we need the job creation and
productivity boost to overcome the looming demographic shift. If we are losing the dynamism in our
society that makes for that creative/destructive energy that propels economic
growth, is there an opportunity for public policy remediation? Perhaps we can get back to using fiscal
policy more aggressively like we did in the 1960s.
Getting
the nation’s productivity picture is important for maintaining and improving
our standard of living as we go on – human progress is linked with economic
development and democratic societies function best when that progress is
broadly shared. So, by raising the GDP measurement issue for keeping
track of our progress is either a distraction or a key indicator for
consideration. Once again, I think while it is an issue, it is a
side issue to the overall problem of lackluster productivity gains and the long
trendline of contractionary economic policies that have resulted in the United
States emphasizing consumption over savings and investment that have affected
our international trade imbalances as well as our continuous grand fiscal
deficits.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)